Micro I Question Sets

Micro I Question SetsPreference and Utility2018 Aug Prelim Part 1 Q1Consumer Theory2023 June Prelim Part1 Q1 - [IE, SE, Slutsky]2023 June Prelim Part1 Q3 - [SE]2022 June Prelim Part1 Q1 - [welfare and duality]2022 Aug Prelim Part1 Q1 - [duality, slutsky equation]2021 June Prelim Part1 Q1 - [Recover direct utility from indirect one]2021 Aug Prelim Part1 Q1 - [UMP with multiple goods]2020 Oct Prelim Part1 Q1 - [Slutsky equation in elasticity form, engel and cournot aggregation]2020 Oct Prelim Part1 Q2 2020 Aug Prelim Part1 Q3 - [Labor-leisure model]2019 June Prelim Part1 Q12019 June Prelim Part1 Q2 - [Quasilinear utility and welfare]2018 Aug Prelim Part1 Q3 - [duality]2018 June Prelim Part1 Q1 - [Hotelling-Wold Identity] 2018 June Prelim Part1 Q3 - [quasilinear utility function]2019 Aug Prelim Part 1 Q1 - [Integrability]Uncertainty2022 June Prelim Part1 Q3 - [Insurance problem]2021 June Prelim Part1 Q22018 Aug Prelim Part1 Q2Producer Theory2023 June Prelim Part1 Q2 - [Cost function]2022 Aug Prelim Part1 Q3 - [Production and uncertainty]2021 Aug Prelim Part1 Q22020 Oct Prelim Part1 Q3 - [Conditional demand and Cost function]2020 Aug Prelim Part1 Q1 - [Short-run and long run Cost function]2019 June Prelim Part1 Q3 - [Production function]2019 Aug Prelim Part1 Q2 - [Profit max and Hotelling lemma]2019 Aug Prelim Part1 Q3 - [perfect competition and comparative analysis]2018 Aug Prelim Part1 Q5 - [Profit max problem]2018 June Prelim Part1 Q2Partial Equilibrium2021 June Prelim Part1 Q3 - [perfect competition]2021 Aug Prelim Part1 Q3 - [perfect competition]2022 June Prelim Part1 Q2 - [partial equilibrium]2022 Aug Prelim Part1 Q22018 June Prelim Part1 Q4Price Discrimination2018 Aug Prelim Part1 Q4Principal Agent Problem2020 Aug Prelim Part1 Q2

Preference and Utility

2018 Aug Prelim Part 1 Q1

[5 points] Show that U(x)=U(f(x1,x2),x3) satisfies the conventional definition of (weak) separability; i.e., show that the marginal rate of substitution between x1 and x2 is invariant to changes in x3.

By the chain rule, we can write the MRS as,

(1)MRS12=Ux1Ux2=fx1fx2

which is invariant to x3.

 

Consumer Theory

2023 June Prelim Part1 Q1 - [IE, SE, Slutsky]

[20 points] Consider a simple quasi-linear utility function of the form U(x,y)=x+lny​​​. (a) Calculate the income effect for each good and the income elasticity of demand for each good. (b) Calculate the substitution effect for each good. Also calculate the compensated own-price elasticity of demand for each good. (c) Show that the Slutsky equation applies to this function. (d) Show that the elasticity form of the Slutsky equation also applies to this function.

Caution

The formula of income effect may be incorrect.

(a)

The Utility max problem is,

(2)maxU(x,y)=x+lnys.t. p1x+p2y=w

Now let's consider the interior solution first. (p1<w)

Solving the utility max problem, we have the marshalian demand for both goods,

(3)x(p,w)=wp11y(p,w)=p1p2

The income effect, xjxiw

  • For x: yxw=yp1

  • for y: xyw=0

Income elasticity of demand: xwwx

  • For x: xwwx=1

  • For y: ywwy=0.

Then, consider the corner solution case, the marshalian demands for both goods are,

(4)x(p,w)=0,y(p,w)=wp2

The income effect:

  • For x: zero

  • For y: xyw=0

Income elasticity of demand: xwwx

  • For y:1

(b)

Solve the expenditure min problem, (consider the interior solution first),

(5)xh(p,u)=ulnp1+lnp2yh(p,u)=p1p2

Substitution effect:

  • For x: xp2=1p2

  • For y: yp1=1p2​​

Then consider the corner solution,

(6)xh(p,u)=0,yh(p,u)=eu

In this cqase both substitution effects are zero.

(c)

Check the slutsky equation:

(7)xipj=hipjxjxiw

It holds for interior solution.

For corner solution, it also holds with LHS and RHS are both 0.

(d)

Check the slutsky equation in elasticity form,

(8)ϵij=ϵijhαjϵiw

It will hold.

 

2023 June Prelim Part1 Q3 - [SE]

[15 points] John Maynard gets $3 of lunch money per week from his Mom. He only likes peanut butter and jelly sandwiches and this is all he eats for lunch. Peanut butter is sold at $0.05 per ounce and jelly at $0.10 per ounce, whereas bread is provided for free from the school cafeteria. J.M. is a particular eater and always makes his sandwiches with exactly 1 ounce of jelly and 2 ounces of peanut butter. (a) how much peanut butter and jelly will J.M. buy with his lunch money per week in order to maximize his utility?

15 ounce of jelly and 30 ounce of peanut butter. NOte that jelly and peanut butter are perfect complements.

(b) Suppose the price of jelly increases to $0.15​ per ounce. How much of each commodity will J.M. buy after this price increase?

12 ounce of jelly and 24 ounce of peanut butter.

(c) by how much would his allowance need to increase to compensate him for the price increase?

$0.75.

(d) In what sense does this problem involve only one commodity, namely peanut-butter-and-jelly sandwiches? Write the demand function for peanut-butter-and-jelly sandwiches.

Suppose the income is w and the price of sandwich is p,

then the demand for sandwich would be x=wp.

(e) Discuss the results of this problem in terms of income and substitution effects involved in the demand for jelly.

if the price ratio changes, the substitution effect will be zero because jelly and peanut butter are complements. so demand for jelly change is only attributed to the income effect.

 

2022 June Prelim Part1 Q1 - [welfare and duality]

[10 points ] A consumer with income y0 faces prices p0 and enjoys utility u0=v(p0,y0). When prices change to p1, the cost of living is affected. To gauge the impact of these price changes, define a cost of living index as the ratio:

(9)I(p0,p1,u0)e(p1,u0)e(p0,u0).

(a) Show that I(p0,p1,u0) is greater (less than) than unity as the outlay necessary to maintain base utility u0 rises (falls).

By Sheppard's lemma,

(10)e(p,u)pi=xih(p,u)>0

Therefore if some elements of p increases, i.e. for some pi1>pi0 and other ji, pj1=pj0, then e(p1,u0)>e(p0,u0), which implies that I(p0,p1,u0)e(p1,u0)e(p0,u0)>1.

(b) Suppose consumer income also changes from y0 to y1. Show that the consumer will be better off in the final period whenever y1y0 is greater than the cost of living index I(p0,p1,u0)​​.

By the duality,

(11)y0=e(p0,u(p0,y0))=e(p0,u0)y1=e(p1,u(p1,y1))=e(p1,u1)

Hence,

(12)y1y0=e(p1,u0)e(p0,u0)e(p1,u1)e(p1,u0)=I(p0,p1,u0)e(p1,u1)e(p1,u0)

Therefore, devide I for both sides, we obtain,

(13)y1y0/I(p0,p1,u0)=e(p1,u1)e(p1,u0)

So, suppose y1y0 is greater than the cost of living index I(p0,p1,u0).

(14)e(p1,u1)e(p1,u0)>1e(p1,u1)>e(p1,u0)

which imlies u1>u0 (The consumer is better off) under the final period with price p1 since eu>0.

 

2022 Aug Prelim Part1 Q1 - [duality, slutsky equation]

[20 points]The utility function for goods x and y is given by:

(15)U(x,y)=x0.5y0.5

(a) Calculate the uncompensated (Marshallian) demand functions for x and y.

Suppose the price for x is px and the price for y is py. and the income of the consumer is w. By solving the UMP, we have the marshallian demand as follows

(16)x(p,w)=w2px, y(p,w)=w2py

(b) Compute the expenditure function and then use the Shephard's lemma to compute the compensated (Hicksian) demand functions for x and y.

By duality, the expenditure function is

(17)e(p,u)=e(p,v(p,w))

Then indirect utility is

(18)v(p,w)=w2px0.5py0.5

Then the expenditure function is

(19)e(p,u)=2upx0.5py0.5

By the Shephard's lemma, the Hicksian demand functions are,

(20)xh(p,u)=epx=upy0.5px0.5yh(p,u)=epy=upx0.5py0.5

(c) Compute the total effect of a price change in px on the Marshallian demand for good x​​​ and prove that Slutsky equation holds in this example.

Check for x,

(21)xpy=0=xhpy=u2px0.5py0.5yxww4pxpy

The slutsky equation holds since u2px0.5py0.5=w4pxpy.

 

2021 June Prelim Part1 Q1 - [Recover direct utility from indirect one]

[15 points] Derive consumer's direct utility function if her indirect utility function has the following form:

(22)v(p,y)=yp1αp2β,α,β<0

and prices are normalized by income, i.e., p1=P1M and p2=P2M such that the budget constraint is p1x1+p2x2=1​​.

By Roy's identity,

(23)x1=vp1vy=αyp1x2=vp2vy=βyp2

Rearrangement:

(24)p1=αyx1p2=βyx2

The direct utility is then,

(25)u(x1,x2)=v(p,1)=Ax1αx2β

where A=ααββ.

 

 

2021 Aug Prelim Part1 Q1 - [UMP with multiple goods]

[20 points] The n-good Cobb-Douglas utility function is given by:

(26)u(x)=Ai=1nxiαi

where A>0 and i=1nαi=1​. (a) Derive the Marshallian demand functions.

The Marshallian demand for good i is,

(27)xi(p,w)=αiwpi

(b) Derive indirect utility function.

Indirect utility,

(28)v(p,w)=Awi=1n(αipi)αi

(c) Compute the expenditure function.

By duality, e(p,u)=e(p,v(p,w)),

(29)e(p,u)=uAi=1n(αipi)αi=uAin(piαi)αi

(d) Compute the Hicksian demands.

By Sheppard's lemma,

(30)xh(p,u)=epi=uαiAjin(pjαj)αjpiαi1αiαi

 

2020 Oct Prelim Part1 Q1 - [Slutsky equation in elasticity form, engel and cournot aggregation]

[15 points] Barbara consumes 2 goods. We know the following three features of her Marshallian demands: α1=13;η2=1 and ϵ11M=1, where α1 is the budget share of good 1 , η2 is the income elasticity of good 2 and ϵ11M is the Marshallian own price elasticity of good

Based on this information, please calculate: (a) η1​ (income elasticity of good 1 );

By engel aggregation,

(31)α1η1+α2η2=1

We solve η1=1.

(b) ϵ21M​ (Marshallian cross price elasticity of good 2 with respect to price of good 1);

By cournot aggregation,

(32)α1ϵ11M+α2ϵ21M+α1=0

We solve ϵ21M=0. and similarly we solve

(c) ϵ12h and ϵ21h​ (Hicksian cross-price elasticities).

By the Slutsky equation,

(33)ϵijM=ϵijhαjηi

We solve ϵ21h=13.

For ϵ21h, since x2hp1=x1hp2,

(34)ϵ12h=x1hp2p2x1=x2hp1p2x1=x2hp1p1x2x2p2x1p1=ϵ21hα2α1=23

2020 Oct Prelim Part1 Q2

[20 points] Guillermo is a first-grader in a public school in Guadalajara. His Mom packs his lunch every morning before he goes to school. The lunch consists of 2 slices of bread and 5 slices of cheese. Guillermo's utility function is given by U(B,C)=B23C13​ where B​ stands for bread and C​​​ stands for cheese. One morning his Mom decides that she is tired of packing his lunch and instead would give him 100 pesos to spend freely on bread and cheese at fixed prices. (a) What should be the prices of bread and cheese to induce Guillermo to consume the same daily ration of 2 slices of bread and 5 slices of cheese?

Skip

 

2020 Aug Prelim Part1 Q3 - [Labor-leisure model]

[15 points] Assume a slightly modified labor-leisure model where a person supplies L hours of labor and consumes two goods: leisure denoted by Z and composite good denoted by C. It takes tZ and tC time to consume one unit of Z and C and the prices of goods Z and C are pZ and pC, respectively. The person's utility function is given by U(Z,C), the budget constraint is given by pZZ+pCC=M+wL where M is non-labor income and w is the wage rate, and the time constraint is given by tZ+tC+L=T, where T denotes total available time. You can think about (pZ+wtZ) and (pC+wtC) as the full prices of Z and C.

Caution

It looks like the time constraint should be tZZ+tCC+L=T. Typo in the original question.

(a) Substituting for L, you can merge two constraints into one, and then set-up utility maximization problem with respect to only budget constraint to obtain Marshallian demand functions for Z and C. Write the general form of these two Marshallian functions as ZM= ZM() and CM=CM() making sure that all arguments of these demand functions are correctly included.

Merging two constraints together,

(35)(pZ+wtZ)Z+(pC+wtC)C=M+wT

Then set up the UMP,

(36)maxU(Z,C),s.t. (pZ+wtZ)Z+(pC+wtC)C=M+wT

We can derive the Marshallian demand in general form,

(37)ZM=ZM(pZ+wtZ,pC+wtC,M+wT)CM=CM(pZ+wtZ,pC+wtC,M+wT)

(b) Formulate the dual of this problem where the agent minimizes the non-labor income M subject to constant utility constraint U(Z,C)=u0 to obtain the Hicksian demand functions. Write the general form of these two Hicksian functions Zh=Zh() and Ch=Ch() and indirect expenditure function e()=M​ making sure that all arguments of these functions are correctly included.

Hicksian demand:

(38)Zh=Zh(pZ+wtZ,pC+wtC,u0)Ch=Ch(pZ+wtZ,pC+wtC,u0)

Indirect expenditure function,

(39)e(p,u0)=(pZ+wtZ)Zh(pZ+wtZ,u0)+(pC+wtC)Ch(pC+wtC,u0)

(c) Using the fundamental identity for leisure Z, derive the Slutsky equation for the change in the wage rate w​.

Caution

Not quite sure about this answer. It appears that the derivation of ZMM is incorrect.

By duality, ZM=ZM(pZ+wtZ,pC+wtC,e(p,u0))

Take dervitive w.r.t w for both sides,

(40)ZMw=ZMpZtZ+ZMpCtC+ZMM(tZZh+(PZ+tZw)Zhw+tCCh+(PC+tCw)Chw)
(41)ZMw=tZZhpZ+tCChpC+ZMM((PZ+tZw)Zhw+(PC+tCw)Chw)

which is the Slutcky equation for the change in the wage rate w

(d) Derive the condition for the substitution effect to be positive, i.e., Zhw>0. With the substitution effect being positive, what is the requirement on the income effect in order for the total effect of the change in the wage rate on leisure to be negative, i.e. ZMw<0​​​.

 

 

2019 June Prelim Part1 Q1

[15 points] Consider a consumer with the so called Stone-Geary utility function:

(42)U=(x1c1)α(x2c2)β,α+β=1

where ci are interpreted as minimum subsistence levels of xi, for i=1,2. (a) Derive the consumer's Hicksian demand functions for xi.

minp1+p2x2st(x1c1)α(x2c2)βu=0L=p1x1+p2x2λ((x1c1)α(x2c2)βu)[x1]:p1λα(x1c1)α1(x2c2)β=0[x2]:p2λβ(x1c1)α(x2c2)β1=0

(43)p1p2=αβx2c2x1c1p1(1α)(x1c1)=p2α(x2c2)
(44)x2h=c2+u(p1p2)(1αα)αx1h=c1+u(p2p1)α(α1α)α

 

(b) Derive the expenditure function.

Skip

(c) Compare the expenditure function that you obtained in (b) with the expenditure function you would obtain in case where a consumer's utility function was of a simple Cobb-Douglas form U=x1αx2β,α+β=1​​. Explain the difference between the two expenditure functions?

Skip

 

2019 June Prelim Part1 Q2 - [Quasilinear utility and welfare]

[15 points] Suppose that the consumer's preferences can be represented by the quasilinear utility function:

(45)U=f(x1)+x2,f>0,f<0

(a) Show that the consumer indifference curves are vertically parallel, i.e. their slope depends only on x1 and not on x2 and confirm that the income elasticity of demand for good 1 is zero.

For each indiffernce curve x2=u¯f(x1), the slope of the IC is x2x1=f(x1), which is uncorrelated with x2​.

  • Cornor solution: x1=0, then income effect would be zero.

  • Interior solution:

    From the foc, we know f(x1)=p1p2, then take derivitives w.r.s. w to both sides, we have

    (46)f(x1)x1w=0

    Since f<0 so we have x1w=0

Then we can confirm the income elasticity of demand is,

(47)x1wwx1=0

(b) Derive the expressions for CV and EV for changes in p1​​ using expenditure function and show that these welfare measures are equal.

Caution

The original answer for this question is not precise, because of the improper specification on x2.

(48)CV(p0,p1,u0)=e(p1,u0)e(p0,u0)EV(p0,p1,u1)=e(p1,u1)e(p0,u1)

So,

(49)CVEV=e(p1,u0)p11x10+p21x20e(p1,u1)p11x11+p21x21+e(p0,u1)p10x11+p20x21e(p0,u0)p10x10+p20x20=(p21p20)(x20x21)

This is because the MRS is always equal to f(x1), so x1 should be the same under the same price, no matter the utility level. i.e. p11x10=p11x11 and p10x11=p10x10.

And we assume no price change in p2 so p21=p20. Thus we have CVEV=0​. these welfare measures are equal.

Xiaoyi: 我感觉 e(p1,u0)=p11x10+p21x20 似乎是有问题的。当price变化的时候,Hicksian demand x(p,u) 也需要随price变化才对。这里应该是e(p1,u0)=p11x11+p20x21​ (因为price for good 2并没有改变,所以不用区分1和0)

There should be four x2s (before and after price change on two different utility level). However, the differences between x2s under the same price ratio but different utility level should be the same (because x1 will not change under the same price and the difference between the utility all comes from x2). This property gurantees that CV=EV.

(c) What is the relationship between the change in the Marshallian consumer surplus and the EV and CV measures in this case? Provide a proof of your answer.

Conclusion: ΔCV=EV=CS.

By defination,

(50)ΔCS(p0,p1,w)=p10p11x1(p,w)dp1
(51)EV(p0,p1,u1)=p10p11x1h(p,u1)dp1
(52)CV(p0,p1,u1)=p10p11x1h(p,u0)dp1

To show they are equivalent, we have to show x1h(p,u1)=x1h(p,u0)=x1(p). (We know from (a) that the Marshallian demand for good 1 does not depend on income w, so x1(p,w)=x1(p)).

The indirect utility could be write in this way,

(53)v(p,w)=p1f(x1(p))+p2x2(p,w)=p1f(x1(p))+p2(wx1(p))

By duality, we can derive the expenditure function,

(54)e(p,u)=up1f(x1(p))+p2x1(p)p2

And obviously we can derive the Hicksian demand for x1 by Sheppard's lemma:

(55)x1h(p,u)=ep1=x1h(p)

which is independent to u.

Therefore, x1h(p,u1)=x1h(p,u0)=x1(p). So we have ΔCV=EV=CS​.

 

2018 Aug Prelim Part1 Q3 - [duality]

[20 points] Consumer 1 has expenditure function e1(p1,p2,u1)=u1p1p2 and consumer 2 has utility function u2(x1,x2)=43x13x2α. (a) What are the Marshallian demand functions for each of the two goods by each of the consumers? Denote the income of consumer 1 by M1 and the income of consumer 2 by M2. Notice there will be 4 demand functions in total.

For consumer 🥇

The indirect utility function is,

(56)v(p,M1)=M1p1p2

Then, applying the Roy's identity, we can obtain,

(57)x11(p,M1)=M12p1x21(p,M1)=M12p2

For consumer 🥈

(58)x12(p,M2)=3M2(α+3)p1x22(p,M2)=αM2(α+3)p2

(b) For what value(s) of the parameter α will there exist aggregate (both consumers) demand functions for x1 and x2​ that are independent of the distribution of income among consumers.

α=3.

 

2018 June Prelim Part1 Q1 - [Hotelling-Wold Identity]

[10 points] Using Hotelling-Wold identity, derive the consumer's inverse Marshallian demand functions p1(x1,x2) and p2(x1,x2) when the utility functions is of the Cobb-Douglas form u(x1,x2)=Ax1αx21α, for 0<α<1. Prices p1=P1M and p2=P2M are normalized by income and x1 and x2​​ denote quantities of goods in question.

`Apply the Hotelling-Wold identity,

(59)pi(x)=u(x)/xij=1nxj(u(x)/xj).

 

2018 June Prelim Part1 Q3 - [quasilinear utility function]

[15 points] An individual receives utility from leisure hours H and from consumption C and has the utility function given by U(H,C)=C+40ln(H). The hourly wage rate is given by w, the non-labor income is N, the price of consumption is p=1 and there is no saving. There are 16 hours in the day that can be devoted to labor L and leisure H; the remaining 8 hours the person has to sleep where, of course, she cannot work while sleeping and also sleeping does not enhance utility. (a) Write the individual's full income constraint and interpret it.

The full income constraint is:

(60)C+wH=16w

The opportunity cost of having one unit of leisure is w unit of consumption.

(b) Set up the utility maximization problem and solve for the demand equations for H and C. Throughout, except in question (e), assume there is an interior solution.

(61)maxU(H,C)=C+40ln(H)s.t.C+wH=16w

Assuming there is an interior solution, the Marshalian demand for H and C are,

(62)H=40wC=16w40

(c) Is the demand for leisure always downward sloping with this utility function?

The demand for leisure is always downward sloping w.r.t. w.

(d) Write out the individual supply function for labor. Is it always upward sloping with respect to wage rate?

(63)L=16H=1640w

Assuming the interior solution, it will be always upward sloping.

(e) Would this person ever choose not to work? If so, with what wages?

This player may choose not to work, in that case we have, H=16,C=0,L=0.

When w<2.5, there is no labor supply.

(f) Find the slope of an indifference curve with C on the vertical axis and H on the horizontal axis.

1H.

(g) Would an incease in non-labor income N​​​​​​​ affect the amount of labor supplied? Explain the intuition behind your answer.

No. Because change in H does not contain any income effect because of the quasi-linear utility function. To be more straightforward, consider the new budget constraint: C+wH=16w+I. And the new marshallian demand functions are,

(64)H=40wC=16w+I40w

So, non-labor income does not have any impact on leisure H​.

The intuition behind: the decision of leisure only depends on its opportunity cost (relative to consumption).

2019 Aug Prelim Part 1 Q1 - [Integrability]

[15 points] Consider a Cobb-Douglas utility function U(x1,x2)=x1x2​ and show that the corresponding system of Marshallian demand functions satisfy all conditions required for integrability. Just to make sure you remember what these conditions are, you need to show: (a) budget balanceness (Walras law),

The Marshallian demand function,

(65)x1(p,w)=w2p1x2(p,w)=w2p2

Then the Walras law hold because p1x1+p2x2=w.

(b) homogeneity of degree zero in prices and income,

Easy to show.

(c) symmetry of the Slutsky matrix, and

The Slutsky matrix is,

(66)S=[w4p12w4p1p2w4p1p2w4p22]

which is obviously symmetric.

(d) negative semidefiniteness of the Slutsky matrix.

First leading principal minor 0(<0)

Second leading principal minor 0 (=0).

which is negative semidefinite

 

Uncertainty

2022 June Prelim Part1 Q3 - [Insurance problem]

[20 points] Consider the following optimal insurance problem: An agent with preferences represented by an expected utility function has a deterministic initial wealth w>0 and faces a risk of losing L such that 0<L<w. The agent can purchase insurance at a premium ρ(0,1) per one dolar of coverage to be paid in case of loss. The probability of loss is π(0,1) and there is nothing the agent can do to affect that probability, i.e. there is no moral hazard. The agent is strictly risk averse with the Bernoulli utility function strictly increasing and twice differentiable. Suppose that ρ>π, i.e., the premium is not actuarially fair. (a) Show that the optimal insurance amount a is less than the full insurance.

Solve for the optimal insurance amount a

The expected utility under optimal insurance could be specified as:

(67)EU=maxa(1π)U(wρa)+πU(wL+(1ρ)a)

The FOC:

(68)U(wρa)U(wL+(1ρ)a)=π1π1ρρ=πρπρρπ<1

since ρ>π.

Since the consumer is assumed to be strictly risk averse, U<0.

Then, U(wρa)<U(wL+(1ρ)a)wρa>wL+aρa, which implies L>a.

(b) Show that the agent's demand for insurance is an increasing function of the amount of loss L​.

From the FOC:

(69)U(wρa)U(wL+(1ρ)a)=π1π1ρρ

Let π1π1ρρ=A, we can write the FOC condition in this way:

(70)U(wρa)=AU(wL+(1ρ)a)

Take derivative w.r.t. L for both sides,

(71)ρU(wρa)aL=AU(wL+(1ρ)a)[1+(1ρ)aL]

Rearranging, we can derive,

(72)aL=U(wL+(1ρ)a)ρU(wρa)+(1ρ)AU(wL+(1ρ)a)

Since the consumer is assumed to be strictly risk averse, U<0, both the numerator and deminator are negative, so aL>0, denamd for insurance is an increasing funtction of the loss.

2021 June Prelim Part1 Q2

[15 points] Suppose an individual lives for two periods; his goods are x1, the amount consumed in period 1 , and x2 the amount consumed in period 2 . His utility function over pairs (x1,x2) is:

(73)u(x1,x2)=ln(x1)+ln(x2)

At the beginning of period 1 , he has an amount of wealth y>0, which can be allocated to three purposes:

Find the choice of x1,b,z that maximizes expected utility E[u(x1,x2)], subject to the budget constraint x1+b+zy

The marginal expected utiltity is positive, so we write the budget contraint as an equation.

Set up the lagrange function:

(74)L=p[lnx1+ln(b+Rz)]+(1p)[lnx1+lnb]λ[x1+b+zy]

The FOCs:

(75)[x1]:px1+1px1λ=0[b]:pb+Rz+1pbλ=0[z]:pRb+Rz+λ=0

Plus the budget constraints,

Rearranging:

  • b=(1p)RR1x1

  • z=pR1R1x1

And plus it into the budget constraint, we have x1=2y.

Then, b=(1p)RR1y2, z=pR1R1y2.

 

2018 Aug Prelim Part1 Q2

[5 points] Consider a utility function in income and prices:

(76)U(p,y)=w(p)lny+v(p)

and relying on the concept (coefficient) of relative risk aversion, determine the type of risk preferences that this utility function describes.

 

 

 

Producer Theory

2023 June Prelim Part1 Q2 - [Cost function]

[15 points] For a general strictly quasi-concave production function q=f(x1,x2,,xn), assume that in the short-run x1 is fixed at some x¯1 level and show that: (a) the long-run average cost curve (LAC) is the lower envelope of the entire family of short-run average cost curves (SACs) obtained by varying x¯1​.

(b) the long-run average cost curve is tangent to only one short-run average cost curve at the minimum of that SAC curve; at that point minSAC=minLAC​.

Caution

  1. How do we rigorously show that LAC SAC.

  2. how do we show there is only one q satisfies the (???)?

Let C(w,q) be the long run total cost function and SC(w,w¯,q;x¯1) be the short run total cost function.

The long run cost function solves the cost minimization problem c(w,y)minxR+nwx s.t. f(x)y.

And in the short run, we solve the sc(w,w,y;x)minxwx+wx s.t. f(x,x)y​.

It is obvious to claim that c(w,y)sc(w,w,y;x)

We know that the long run total cost and the short run total cost are identical when x¯1 is fixed at the optimal value x¯1 that producer will choose in the long run,

(77)C(w,q)=SC(w,w¯1,q;x¯1)

Otherwise, we know that the

If we devide both sides by q, it gives us the equation of average cost,

(78)LAC(w,q)=SAC(w,w¯1,q;x¯1)

Otherwise, LAC(w,q)>SAC(w,w¯1,q;x¯1)

because we have chose the optimal input to minimize the short run cost, so the optimal amount x¯1 should satisfy:

(79)SAC(w,w¯1,q;x¯1)x¯1=0

Now, differentiate the equation (???) w.r.t. q on both sides,

(80)LAC(w,q)q=SAC(w,w¯1,q;x¯1)q+SAC(w,w¯1,q;x¯1(q))x¯1x¯1(q)q=0

Then, there exist only one q such that

(81)LAC(w,q)q=SAC(w,w¯1,q;x¯1)q=0

Which implies minSAC=minLAC.

2022 Aug Prelim Part1 Q3 - [Production and uncertainty]

[15 points] The market for high quality (Beluga) caviar is dependent on the weather. If the weather is good, rich people party a lot and caviar sells for $30 per ounce. If the weather is bad, it sells for only $20 per ounce. Caviar has low shelf life and will not keep fresh for more than a week. A small caviar producer (sturgeon fisherman) has a cost function given by:

(82)TC=12q2+5q+100

where q indicates the weekly caviar production. Production decisions must be made before the weather (and the price of caviar) is known, but it is common knowledge that good weather and bad weather each occur with probability of 0.5 .

(a) How much caviar should this firm produce if it wishes to maximize the expected value of its profits?

q=20. and the expected profit would be 100

(b) Suppose this firm is owned by a sole proprietor whose utility function is U=π, where π denotes weekly profits. What is the expected utility associated with the output strategy defined in part (a)?

EU=0.5×2007.0711 .

(c) Can the firm owner obtain a higher utility of profits by producing some output other than that specified in parts (a) and (b)? Explain!

Intuitively Yes. Because the target function of maximizing profit and utility are different. Utility maximization problem gives the optimal utility for sure, which is expected to be higher than the utility of maximization of profit.

Rigorously, we can calculate the exact number of output and uitilty. The firm can maximize their expected utility, which gives q=16.95 and corresponding expected utility is 8.3378.

(d) Suppose the firm can predict next week's price with perfect certainty, but could not influence that price, i.e. the caviar market is perfectly competitive. What production (sales) strategy would maximize the expected profits in this case? What would expected profits be? How do you explain the difference in profits between case (a) and case (d)?

p=MR=MC=q+5.

Therefore, if the price is forcasted to be 20, then q=15, and if the price is expected to be 30, then q=25.

Under this strategy, the expected profit is 112.5. And the expected utility would be 9.0565​.

An improper answer: The case in ((a)) and (d) are very similar to the case of price discrimination. Case in (d) is similar to the firm can charge a different price on two different market with knowing the exact information, while the case in (a) is similar to firm have no information on each separate market. In this case, knowing more information helps the firm get more market power and gain more producer surplus.

 

2021 Aug Prelim Part1 Q2

[15 points] A firms's technology possesses all the usual properties. It produces output using three inputs, with conditional input demands xi(w1,w2,w3,y),i=1,2,3. Some of the following observations are consistent with the cost minimization problem of the firm and some are not. If an observation is inconsistent, explain why. If it is consistent, give an example of a cost or production function to illustrate your point. (a) x2w1>0 and x3w1>0

x1 and x2, x1 and x3 are substitutes, so a Cobb-Douglas production function satisfies this property.

(b) x2w1>0 and x3w1<0

x1 and x2 are substitutes, and x1 and x3 are complements.

(c) x1y<0 and x2y<0 and x3y<0.

All the inputs are inferior. This is inconsistent to any production function.

(d) x1y=0.

No x1 in the production function.

(e) (x1/x2)w3=0​​

 

2020 Oct Prelim Part1 Q3 - [Conditional demand and Cost function]

[15 points] A factor of production is called inferior if the conditional demand for that factor decreases as output increases, that is, x(w,y)y<0​​. (a) Draw a diagram indicating that inferior factors are possible.

 

(b) Show that if the technology is constant returns to scale, then no factors can be inferior.

Since the production function is homogeneous function, so we can decompose the conditional input function x(p,y) as

(83)x(p,y)=yx(p,1)

Therefore, if we take partial derivitives,

(84)xi(p,y)y=xi(p,1)>0.

which implies that no factors can be inferior.

(c) Show that if marginal cost decreases as the price of some factor increases, then that factor must be inferior.

(85)MC=c(w,y)y

By the Young's theorem,

(86)2c(w,y)ywi=xi(w,y)y<0

Which implies that that factor must be inferior.

2020 Aug Prelim Part1 Q1 - [Short-run and long run Cost function]

[15 points] There has been widespread interest in hydroxychloroquine as both a preventative measure and for treating patients with Covid-19. Despite some early studies raising hopes, one subsequent larger scale trial has shown that it is not effective as a treatment. The production of hydroxychloroquine (q) depends on the number of kettles (K) and the number of workers (L) according to the C-D production function q=10K0.5L0.5. If kettles can be rented for v per hour and workers can be hired for w per hour, then the total cost function is given by TC=vK+wL. (a) Derive the total cost function for this hydroxychloroquine production establishment.

Conditional input demand:

(87)L(v,w,q)=q10(vw)1/2K(v,w,q)=q10(wv)1/2

Then we can derive the cost function:

(88)c(v,w,q)=q5v0.5w0.5

(b) Now suppose that the number of kettles is fixed at K¯​​​ in the short run and derive the short-run total cost function for this establishment.

The problem:

(89)minLvK¯+wLs.t.q=10K¯0.5L0.5
(90)L=q2100K¯

The short run cost function:

(91)sc(v,w,q(K¯);K¯)=vK¯+wq2100K¯

(c) Use the envelope procedure and derive the total cost function starting from the short-run total cost function.

We know that the long run cost function is the lower envelope of the entire family of short-run cost curves varying K¯.

By envelope theorem,

(92)sc(w,v,q(K¯);K¯)K¯=c(w,v,q)K¯=0

We can derive K¯=(w100v)1/2q. substitute K¯ back to the short-run cost function,

(93)c(v,w,q)=q5v0.5w0.5

2019 June Prelim Part1 Q3 - [Production function]

[20 points] Consider a labor managed (partnership) law firm whose only decision variable is how many lawyers to employ, each one of them will work identical number of hours. The firm has fixed cost F payable for the firm's fixed capital stock K¯. Hence the production function is given by q=f(N,K¯),fN>0,fNN<0. The firm sells into a perfectly competitive market and receives price p for its services. Since lawyers own the firm, they share its profits such that each lawyer receives compensation y=(pqF)/N. Based on this ownership structure, the objective of this law firm is to maximize income per lawyer, so it solves the following problem:

(94)maxNy=[pf(N,K¯)F]N

(a) Write the first order condition for this problem and interpret the result.

FOC:

(95)pfN(N,K¯)=[pf(N,K¯)F]N

where the LHS is the marginal revenue that hiring one more lawyer, and the RHS is the average income per lawyer. This FOC has an interpretation of the firm will stop hiring new lawyer when hiring one more lawyer become less profitable than their current average income.

 

(b) Evaluate the comparative statics effect of a change in the market price of output p on optimal hiring decision N (Hint: because there is no closed form solution for N you need to rely on the implicit differentiation).

Taking derivitives w.r.t. p for both side of FOC, at N=N

(96)fN+pfNNNp=pfNNp+pfNpfFN2Np

Rearranging,

(97)fN>0pfN>0=[pfNNpfFN2=0pfNN>0]Np

Therefore, the sign ofNp depends on the relative sizes of fN and pfN, which is ambiguous. In other words, if p increases, the marginal profit of each lawyer will rise, however, the average income of workers will increase correspondingly as well. Hence, whether the firm will hire or fire workers depend on which side increases more.

 

(c) Now imagine that the above law firm has the exact same capital structure but is managed as a standard profit maximizing firm who pays each of its lawyers the prevailing market salary w. Write out the objective function for this firm and compute the first order condition with respect to N​​ and interpet the result.

(98)maxNpf(N,K¯)wN

FOC:

(99)pfN=w

Interpretation: Marginal cost = Marginal revenue.

 

(d) Evaluate the comparative statics effect of a change in the market price of output p on the optimal hiring decision N​​​ and contrast the obtained result with the one obtained in (b).

Take derivitive w.r.t. p for the FOC,

(100)fN>0+pfNN<0Np=0

So Np>0​.

In this case, a rise in p will always result an increase in labor demand. This is because the marginal revenue of hiring one additional lawyer is larger as p increases, while the marginal cost w is fixed.

 

2019 Aug Prelim Part1 Q2 - [Profit max and Hotelling lemma]

[15 points] Consider a production function f(x1,x2)=αln(x1)+βln(x2) and assume that α>0 and β>0 and interior solution: (a) calculate profit function for a profit maximizing firm that uses the above technology and faces output price p and input prices w1 and w2,

Profit max problem:

(101)max π=p((αln(x1)+βln(x2))w1x1w2x2

The input demand functions:

(102)x1(w,p)=pαw1,x2(w,p)=pβw2

The profit function,

(103)π(w,p)=p[αln(pαw1)+βln(pβw2)(α+β)]

(b) show that profit function is increasing in price of output,

According to the Hotelling's lemma's result,

(104)π(p,w)p=y(p,w)>0

So the profit function is increasing in price of output.

We can verify this result:

(105)π(p,w)p=αlnx1+βlnx2(α+β)+p[αw1pααw1+βw2pββw2]=αlnx1+βlnx2

(c) show that it is decreasing in factor prices,

Easy to show.

(106)π(p,w)w1=x1<0π(p,w)w2=x2<0

(d) show that it is homogeneous of degree 1 in ( p,w)​​​​​,

(107)π(tw,tp)=tp[αln(tpαtw1)+βln(tpβtw2)(α+β)]=tπ(w,p)

 

(e) show Hotelling's lemma results.

See (b) and (c).

 

2019 Aug Prelim Part1 Q3 - [perfect competition and comparative analysis]

[20 points ] Recall that profit maximizing behavior under perfect competition is equivalent to each firm minimizing its average cost and that minimum average cost occurs when marginal cost equals average cost, i.e.: MC(w1,w2,y)=AC(w1,w2,y). In this situation an interesting question is how does the equilibrium output level y associated with Min AC change when factor prices w1 or w2 change? (a) Evaluate the above comparative statics result, i.e. determine the sign of yw1 when x1 is an inferior factor such that MCw1<0​.

Caution

Is (???) correct?

Since AC=MC,

(108)MCw1=ACw1<0

Therefore, we have,

(109)ACw1=(cy)w1=cw1yyw1cy2<0cw1<yw1cyyw1>cw1AC=x1×AC0

(b) Repeat the same analysis for the case when x1 is a normal factor meaning that MCw1>0. Make sure that you show all relevant work because guessing the correct result without solid analytical reasoning will not count as the correct answer.

 

 

2018 Aug Prelim Part1 Q5 - [Profit max problem]

[10 points] Consider a technology described by y=0 for x1 and y=lnx for x>1. The price of output y is equal to p and the price of the production factor x equals w​​​. Calculate the factor demand, the supply function and the profit function for this technology.

The profit max problem is, and we need to discuss by case,

(110)maxx pywx
  • For x>1,

    (111)maxx plnxwx

    The input demand function:

    (112)x(p,w)=pw

    Supply function: y=lnplnw.

    Profit function: π(p,w)=pln(pw)p.

  • For x1,x=0,y=0,π=0.

 

2018 June Prelim Part1 Q2

[10 points] Show that for any constant returns to scale production function y=f(x), maximizing the profit function π=pf(x)i=1nwixi always leads to zero profit.

For constant returns to scale production function,

(113)f(tx)=tf(x)t>0

Therefore, take derivitives w.r.t. t for both sides,

(114)f(x)=ifi(x)xi

From the prodit max problem, we know wi=pfi(x), then, pf(x)=ipfi(x)wixi, so π=pf(x)i=1nwixi=0.

Partial Equilibrium

2021 June Prelim Part1 Q3 - [perfect competition]

[20 points] An industry consists of many identical firms with cost function c(q)= q2+1. When there are J active firms, each firm faces an identical inverse market demand function p=1015q(J1)q¯ where the other J1 firms produce the same output level q¯. (a) In the short run, suppose there is no entry or exit. What is the market price and quantity in the Cournot equilibrium with J​​ firms. Recall, the Cournot-Nash equilibrium is when all firms individually choose their optimal quantities, taking other firms' actions as given.

The profit each firm:

(115)π=10q15q2(J1)q¯qq21

Therefore, each firm's best response is,

(116)q(q¯)=10(J1)q¯32

And the price is then,

(117)p(q¯)=1732(10(J1)q¯)

(b) In the long run, entry and exit are allowed. What will be the number of active firms?

And in the competitive market, each identical firm would produce the same amount of goods.

(118)q=10(J1)q32

Then, J=1031qq, where q is the optimal production.

And we know that each firm has to have zero economic profit in the long run, so π=10q15q2(J1)q2q21=0. From this we know that q=14.

And J=9.

2021 Aug Prelim Part1 Q3 - [perfect competition]

[15 points] Suppose there are a large number of identical firms in a perfectly competitive industry. Each firm has the long-run average cost curve :

(119)AC(q)=q212q+50

where q is the firm's output. (a) What condition must be satisfied in a long-run equilibrium if we assume no barriers to entry or exit?

In a perfect competitive market, in the long run we have,

(120)p=AC=MC

In other words, AC=MC implies that p=minAC.

(b) What condition must be satisfied in a perfectly competitive industry?

p=MC.

(c) Derive the long-run supply function for this industry.

In the short run, For each firm, the supply function is

(121)p=MC=3q224q+50

In the long run, the supply should be 6N, where N is the number of firms operating in the market.

(d) How much will each individual firm produce in this equilibrium?

q=6. for each firm.

(e) What do you need to know to determine how many firms will exist in this perfectly competitive long-run equilibrium?

We need to know the market demand function.

 

2022 June Prelim Part1 Q2 - [partial equilibrium]

[20 points] Consider a pork processor who buys live hogs from upstream suppliers (hog farmers) and sell pork products to downstream buyers (retail chains, food service companies, etc.). The live hogs buying area is physically constraint by the fact that live animals cannot travel very long distances from farms to slaughter (processing) plants. As a result, processors tend to have considerable market power on the regional markets for live hogs but the downstream market for pork is perfectly competitive.

(a) Consider a monopsony processor and identify the equilibrium price and quantity that would emerge in the market for live hogs and show their relationship to equilibrium price and quantity under the perfectly competitive live hogs market. You can use either graphs, analytical models or verbal arguments to formulate your answers.

In a monopsony market, there is only one processor who dominates the market price by maximizing their profit of production of pork products by choosing the optimal amount of live hogs.

In this case, the market price is determined by MC = MR of production, which is the point A in the following figure ( w and L represents the price and quantity of live hogs). The price is higher than the perfect competition market which the price and equilibrium quantity correspond to point C. (In perfect competition, the market price and quantity is determined by the market demand equals to supply.)

undefined

(b) Now consider a situation where the local government has imposed a moratorium on the construction of new hog farms and grandfathered each existing farmer i with a production quota q¯i in perpetuity. All individual quotas are strictly binding and not transferable across farmers (aggregate quota Σiq¯i=Q¯​​​​ is also binding). Describe the new equilibrium where a monopsony processor buys live hogs under the quota system, i.e. identify new equilibrium price and quantity and compare them to the previous case. In terms of the price they receive for their hogs, are farmers in the monopsonistic market better off with quota or without?

 

 

(c) Now, maintain the quota assumption but relax the monopsony assumption and assume an oligopsony market for live hogs where K identical processors behave as Cournot players. What happens to the equilibrium price for live hogs in the Cournot-Nash equilibrium relative to the pure monopsony case? Can you establish the relationship between the equilibrium price for live hogs and the number of processors in the Cournot-Nash equilibrium?

 

(d) When production controls are in the form of quotas, the quota itself can be viewed as a perfectly inelastic (fixed) production input. Assuming the individual quotas are tradeable, what should determine the quota prices in equilibrium? Assuming the individual quotas can only be bought and sold with the entire farms which they are assigned to, how would you figure out the value (price) of the quota by looking at farm sales?

 

2022 Aug Prelim Part1 Q2

[15 points] Robinson Crusoe is both a producer and a consumer. He has one unit of time, which he can divide between leisure l and work x, hence l+x=1. If he devotes the amount of time x to work then his output is f(x), where f(x) is increasing and strictly concave. Crusoe has a monotone convex preference relation over the set of leisure-consumption pairs (l,c) that is represented by a differentiable utility function U. (a) Formally state the problem that Crusoe's optimal choice of (l,c) solves. The only source of consumption is what is produced, i.e. there are no goods just lying around to be consumed. Illustrate the optimal solution graphically in the consumption-leisure space.

(122)maxU(l,c)s.t.f(1l)=c

(b) Calculate explicitly the solution of Crusoe's problem for f(x)=x and U(l,c)=lc. Hint: You should use the time constraint and express labor in terms of leisure as x=(1l)​.

l=12,c=22.

(c) Show that the marginal rate of substitution between leisure and consumption at the optimal pair (l,c)​​ chosen by Crusoe is equal to the marginal product of labor/leasure, i.e. the slope of the constraint. Explain why!

The slope is 22.

The opportunity cost of one additional unit of leisure is the corresponding output that is given up to be produced and consumed. Therfore, MUl=MUc×MPx.

2018 June Prelim Part1 Q4

[15 points] Death and Taxes is a trendy restaurant in Raleigh. People come there to see other people and to be seen by other people. There is, however, a hard-core of 10 customers per evening who come regularly and don't care how many other people come. The number of additional customers depends on how many people they expect to see that evening. In particular, if people expect that the number of customers in an evening will be x, then the number of people who actually come is given by y=10+0.8x.

(a) solve for the equilibrium nightly attendance.

x=10+0.8xx=50.

(b) Suppose now that one additional hard-core customer joins the group of regulars. Like the other 10 , he eats at Death and Taxes every night no matter how many other people eat there. Solve for the new equilibrium number of nightly customers.

x=55

(c) Suppose that everybody bases expectations about tonight's attendance on the last night attendance and that the last night's attendance is public knowledge. Suppose further that on the first night that Death and Taxes opens, attendance is 20 . What will be the attendance on the second night? What is the limiting value that the attendance will tend towards over time?

26, 50.

 

Price Discrimination

2018 Aug Prelim Part1 Q4

[10 points] Consider a market for a product with two types of potential consumers: those in proportion λ have inverse demand function P=50.5Q, while the remaining 1λ have inverse demand P=10Q. Normalize the total number of consumers to 1 and let c=2 be the constant marginal cost. (a) What is the optimal (profit maximizing) two-part tariff (as a function of λ​ ) that induces both types of consumers to buy the product?

The firm charges a F=9 and p=c=2.

In this case, the profit of the firm is

(123)π=9(λ+1λ)+(pc)0Q=9

 

(b) What is the optimal two-part tariff when only high demand consumers purchase the good?

When only high demand consumers purchase, they charge a F=32.

(124)π=32(1λ)

 

(c) If λ=0.5​​ which of the pricing schemes (a) or (b) yields higher total profit?

scheme (b) yield higher profit.

Principal Agent Problem

2020 Aug Prelim Part1 Q2

[20 points] Consider a simple contracting problem between risk-neutral principal (P) and risk-neutral agent (A) for production of face masks. To obtain a contract A must invest in production capacity I with associated marginal and average cost of c>1, such that the total value of investment is cI. The stream of benefits associated with this investment is b(I), with b(I)I>0 and 2b(I)I2<0. The contract stipulates that P compensates A for his services in the amount of p, after which she becomes the residual claimant on the realized profits. The contract is assumed to be efficient in the sense that it maximizes the joint (both parties) net surplus from contracting.

(a) Derive the expression for A's efficient (first-best) level of investment assuming that the contract is guaranteed under the same conditions for the entire useful life of investment. Draw a graph with benefits on the vertical axis and the investment level on the horizontal axis and indicate the optimal level of investment I.

The efficient level of investment maximizes the aggregate surplus.

(125)maxIb(I)cI

The expression for the efficient level:

(126)b(I)=c

 

(b) Now consider a short-term contract that needs to be renegotiated several times during the useful life of the investment. If the negotiation breaks down, the value of A's investment outside the contract is given by its salvage value r(n,λ,I)=λI(11n). This salvage value depends on the size of the investment I, asset specificity λ[0,1] and the competition for agents measured by the number of principals n1. Since P is assumed to make no investments, the value of her investment outside the contract is naturally zero. Therefore, the total gain from contracting is b(I)r(n,λ,I)>0 because at this point the cost of investment has already been incurred and is thus sunk. Once the contract is up for renewal, the parties bargain to determine A's compensation. Suppose that bargaining enables A to capture a share α[0,1] of the gain from contracting such that the bargained compensation becomes p=r(n,λ,I)+α[b(I)r(n,λ,I)]. Derive the expression for A's optimal investment assuming α=12​​​ and show that it is less than the first best. Illustrate the new point on the same graph you used in (a).

The net profit of the agent is: pcI=12[b(I)+r(n,λ,I)]cI

The FOC:

(127)b(I)=2cλ(11n)

Since λ(11n)1 and c>1, so λ(11n)<c

Then

(128)b(I)=2cλ(11n)>c=b(I)

Since 2b(I)I2<0, I<I, which is less than the first best.

(c) The result you got is known as the problem of hold-up (Williamson). Can you explain what is going on?

The investment level of I in short-term contracts must be lower than the optimal investment level. This is because in short-term contracts, agents cannot fully internalize the marginal benefits brought by investment, and must consider the residual value when the negotiation fails. This leads to a decrease in the agent's actual investment motivation, which leads to a lower investment level than the optimal level.

(d) Evaluate the sign of the following comparative statics results: In and Iλ​​ and provide a commentary.

(129)b(I)In=λn2In=λn2b(I)>0
(130)Iλ=1/n1b(I)>0